Bioethics for Breakfast: Health Reform Unmentionables: Long-Term Care

Bioethics for Breakfast Seminars in Medicine, Law and Society

Anne Montgomery and Sarah Slocum, co-directors of Altarum’s Program to Improve Eldercare, presented at the December 10 Bioethics for Breakfast session, offering perspectives and insight on the topic “Health Reform Unmentionables: Long-Term Care.”

While past Bioethics for Breakfast events were held in person, this year’s series is taking place virtually. The series is generously sponsored by Hall, Render, Killian, Heath & Lyman.

A lot of attention has been given recently to the social, political, ethical, and economic challenges associated with long-term care. Nursing homes and long-term care facilities have suffered during the COVID-19 pandemic, but at the same time, the pandemic has given these issues more public visibility. There are several large questions to consider: What are the major challenges facing long-term care today? How should long-term care be financed? What would motivate individuals to purchase long-term care insurance? What are the consequences for Medicaid if we see increased reliance on Medicaid for long-term care funding (keeping in mind continued growth of the elderly population and dementing illness)? What policy options are available for addressing all these challenges? Should those policy options be left to the states? What, if any, is the role of the federal government?

Discussing financing, proposals, and reforms related to long-term care insurance in the U.S., Sarah Slocum reminded attendees of our present-day circumstances by giving a brief overview of Medicare and Medicaid, beginning in the 1965 when they were passed at the federal level. The original design did not include long-term care. By the 1980s, the version of Medicaid could bankrupt entire families if one member of a married couple needed to enter a nursing home. In the 1990s, spousal impoverishment provisions were enacted to protect the assets of individuals. Many states began regulating long-term care insurance, however, policies remained very expensive and were very hard to market. For those who did choose to purchase long term care insurance, their premiums increased as they got older. Bringing us to the present, Slocum discussed Michigan reforms that began to be planned in 2017. One option that the Michigan legislature will have to consider is a 0.5-1% payroll tax contribution for all individuals to fund a long-term care program. Slocum shared the example of a new program in the state of Washington, noting that watching how well the program does could help inform decisions made in Michigan and other states.

Anne Montgomery then offered insight into policy considerations at the federal level, based on her work in Washington, D.C. The cost of long-term care insurance remains a challenge to many people. Additionally, one in five middle-income seniors will become impoverished, typically turning to Medicaid to cover their long-term care costs. More than half of Americans who enter old age today will have a long-term care need for constant attendance, something that is very costly. Montgomery shared the possibility of federal social insurance, though that possibility depends on how legislation is drafted and considered by Congress. Discussing Medigap, Montgomery suggested adding long-term care services and supports to the existing coverage. Montgomery also brought forth the need for a bigger and better trained long-term care workforce, and the need for other infrastructure and home and community-based service improvements. Montgomery then shared predictions on what the Biden administration may be looking to do beginning in 2021, touching on the Affordable Care Act and the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Innovation. Finally, Montgomery discussed the need for culture change and quality improvement within nursing homes, such as moving to a person-centered model.

The discussion portion of the session included questions about how hospice and palliative care interface with long-term care insurance, how family caregivers could be compensated under a new model, and the overall appetite of the American public for the changes discussed by Slocum and Montgomery.

Related Resources

About the Speakers

Anne Montgomery
Anne Montgomery is Co-Director at Altarum’s Program to Improve Eldercare, where she oversees a portfolio of quality improvement and research projects focused on older adults and long-term services and supports. Montgomery has more than two decades of policy experience working on Medicare, Medicaid and related programs. Montgomery served as a Senior Advisor for the U.S. Senate Special Committee on Aging, where she developed policy included in the Affordable Care Act, including policy to upgrade quality in the nursing home sector; expand options for states offering home and community-based services; improve direct care worker training; and improve state Medicaid assessment processes. Montgomery also worked for the House Ways & Means Committee, the Government Accountability Office and the Alliance for Health Policy in Washington, D.C., and was awarded the Atlantic Fellowship in Public Policy to conduct comparative analysis of family caregiver policy in the U.S. and the UK. Montgomery received an MS in Journalism from Columbia University.

Sarah Slocum
Sarah Slocum joined the Altarum Program to Improve Elder Care in the fall of 2016. As Co-Director of Altarum’s Program to Improve Eldercare, Ms. Slocum strives to improve the quality of life and care for frail elders living with disability. Just prior, she served 13 years as Michigan’s State Long Term Care Ombudsman, leading advocacy for Michigan citizens living in long term care facilities. She has led policy change efforts in the state Medicaid program, long term care regulations, the Certificate of Need program, and with the Michigan legislature. Ms. Slocum has testified on nursing home quality before the U.S. Senate Special Committee on Aging. She has worked for over three decades in aging and long term care advocacy at the state and national levels. Ms. Slocum received an MA in Bioethics from the Michigan State University College of Human Medicine.

About Bioethics for Breakfast:
In 2010, Hall, Render, Killian, Heath & Lyman invited the Center for Ethics to partner on a bioethics seminar series. The Center for Ethics and Hall Render invite guests from the health professions, religious and community organizations, political circles, and the academy to engage in lively discussions of topics spanning the worlds of bioethics, health law, business, and policy. For each event, the Center selects from a wide range of controversial issues and provides two presenters either from our own faculty or invited guests, who offer distinctive, and sometimes clashing, perspectives. Those brief presentations are followed by a moderated open discussion.

Listen: Ethics and Policy Issues of Targeted Cancer Therapies

No Easy Answers in Bioethics logoNo Easy Answers in Bioethics Episode 16

What kinds of challenges currently exist within precision medicine? This episode focuses specifically on targeted cancer therapies, featuring a discussion between Center Professor and Acting Director Dr. Len Fleck and College of Osteopathic Medicine student Stephanie Mackenzie. Dr. Fleck discusses ethics, economic, medical, and health policy issues related to these high-cost therapies. Additionally, he provides insight into how U.S. pricing models for these therapies compare with other countries.

Ways to Listen

This episode was produced and edited by Liz McDaniel in the Center for Ethics. Music: “While We Walk (2004)” by Antony Raijekov via Free Music Archive, licensed under a Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike License. Full episode transcript available.

About: No Easy Answers in Bioethics is a podcast series from the Center for Ethics and Humanities in the Life Sciences in the Michigan State University College of Human Medicine. Each month Center for Ethics faculty and their collaborators discuss their ongoing work and research across many areas of bioethics. Episodes are hosted by H-Net: Humanities and Social Sciences Online.

Bioethics for Breakfast: Medicare for All: What Should That Mean?

Bioethics for Breakfast Seminars in Medicine, Law and SocietyStacey Hettiger and Rick Murdock presented at the September 26th Bioethics for Breakfast event, offering perspectives and insight on the topic “Medicare for All: What Should That Mean?”

“Medicare for All” has become a contentious political slogan. Advocates for various versions of the slogan want to see everyone have access to needed and affordable health care. Critics see all versions of the slogan as unaffordable and hostile to individual liberty. Is compromise possible? Can we have some level of affordable health care for everyone in our society? Can this be accomplished in ways that are congruent with our most fundamental political values? Event speakers addressed these questions and more, inviting response and discussion from those in attendance.

This year’s Bioethics for Breakfast series centers on the theme “Is There a Cure for Our Sick Health Care System?”

About the Speakers

Stacey Hettiger
Stacey Hettiger is Director of Medical and Regulatory Policy at Michigan State Medical Society. Her responsibilities include developing materials, programming, and member communications in the areas of legal and regulatory compliance and State and Federal quality initiatives. This includes advocacy and outreach on issues affecting the delivery of health care such as HIPAA, physician payment models and incentives, and practice transformation. Prior to joining MSMS, Stacey worked for twenty years in the Michigan State Legislature.

Rick Murdock
Rick Murdock retired from the Michigan Association of Health Plans in 2017 after 12 years as executive director, and has since been consulting with the MAHP Foundation to coordinate the Michigan ACE (adverse childhood experiences) Initiative. Prior to joining MAHP, he spent three years working in the Michigan legislature, followed by 18 years in the State Budget Office (mental health and Medicaid and health planning). Additionally he spent 6 years in Medicaid administering the Medicaid managed care program. He has a master’s degree in public health from the University of Michigan School of Public Health.

About Bioethics for Breakfast:
In 2010, Hall, Render, Killian, Heath & Lyman invited the Center for Ethics to partner on a bioethics seminar series. The Center for Ethics and Hall Render invite guests from the health professions, religious and community organizations, political circles, and the academy to engage in lively discussions of topics spanning the worlds of bioethics, health law, business, and policy. For each event, the Center selects from a wide range of controversial issues and provides two presenters either from our own faculty or invited guests, who offer distinctive, and sometimes clashing, perspectives. Those brief presentations are followed by a moderated open discussion.

Medicare For All: This Is Going to Hurt

Bioethics in the News logoThis post is a part of our Bioethics in the News series

By Leonard M. Fleck, PhD

Let me start with a clear unequivocal commitment in response to the January Washington Post editorial regarding Medicare for All. From the perspective of what a just and caring society ought to be, “Medicare for All” should be embraced, especially when compared to the costly, fragmented, unjust, inefficient health care financing system we currently have in the United States. For openers, if we abolished private health insurance, we would immediately achieve administrative savings of about $300 billion. We would have the same administrative efficiency as Canada. We would also have a more egalitarian approach for financing and accessing needed health care. What we would NOT have is effective health care cost control. Developing that ability would be ethically, politically, and economically painful.

If we literally mean Medicare for all, recall that substantial co-payments are part of Medicare, which is why a majority of Medicare recipients purchase a private supplementary plan to cover that financial risk. That necessary additive supplement represents a significant compromise of the egalitarian ideal that Medicare is supposed to represent. That represents financial and ethical pain.

The most painful parts of Medicare for All would be three things: (1) the transition itself from employer-funded health care; (2) the scope of the benefit package; and (3) effective cost control. Currently, the federal government covers about $1.5 trillion in health care costs (mostly Medicare, Medicaid and the Veterans Affairs system) out of total health spending in the U.S. in 2017 of $3.5 trillion. Virtually all of that spending would become part of the federal budget. To fund that, the federal government would have to recapture through taxes all that employers (and employees) currently contribute to the cost of their health plan. This would be neither easy nor equitable because of the huge variation from one employer to another, both in scope of coverage and allocation of costs.

Individual holding Medicare For All sign
An individual is photographed holding a sign up above their head that reads “Love it! Improve it! Medicare For All!” Image source: Glyn Lowe PhotoWorks/Flickr Creative Commons

Second, what should be the scope of the benefit package? Should it be whatever Medicare covers now, which is reasonably comprehensive? However, many employers offer more comprehensive benefit packages. That would mean employees had to accept a diminished benefit package. Alternatively, the federal government could upgrade Medicare to that optimal level. That would add substantially to that $3.5 trillion in current health spending, and the taxes needed to finance that upgrade. This is political and economic pain. We could permit private insurance upgrades, as in the UK, or forbid such upgrades, as in Canada. Either way, political and ethical pain is the result.

Third, the most painful problem would be controlling health care costs, as the former Princeton economist Uwe Reinhardt has noted with his notion of Great Equations, Cost Control = Income Control or Care Control. Every dollar in health care costs represents someone’s income, and that particular someone does not want to sacrifice their own income for a vague greater good, or someone else’s care. This is the problem of health care rationing.

Political conservatives have denounced health care rationing and contended that “human life is priceless,” (to the benefit of pharmaceutical companies). Liberals have argued that we should not be “throwing granny off a cliff” (when Paul Ryan pushed for privatizing Medicare). In either case, rationing is in fact pervasive in the U.S. health care system. We mostly ration by ability to pay, sometimes in the form of employer-restricted very thin health care coverage or coverage with very high deductibles. We collectively avert our eyes from this private pain.

As I have written extensively, this is essentially invisible health care rationing (Fleck, 71-99). It is widely dispersed among hundreds of thousands of employers. An employer might refuse to cover an extraordinarily expensive (but effective) life-prolonging drug for an employee who dies prematurely because of that denial. The obituary will not list rationing as the cause of death, and the Washington Post will not cover this unjust death.

If Medicare covers everyone, however, then decisions by Medicare not to fund these extraordinarily expensive targeted cancer therapies for patients with metastatic cancer become front-page headlines in the Washington Post and the lead story on Fox News. Pharmaceutical companies become the frontline troops in attacking the bureaucrats for having hearts of stone and consciences of jelly: “Human life is priceless (and pharmaceutical profits too).” In fairness, hospitals, physicians, home health agencies, long-term care facilities and so on will all resist health care cost control. They are all doing good work. Why, they will ask rhetorically, would a just and caring society seek to constrain such good work?

Healthy taxpayers want health care costs controlled; taxpayers with metastatic cancer want access to anything and everything medicine offers that might prolong their life, no matter the cost (because they paid all those taxes) (Eddy). This is irrational (but real). One refrain (seen as politically safe) is to get rid of waste and inefficiency in the health care system. Nothing obviously irrational or unethical about that, except that one person’s waste and inefficiency is another person’s life-prolonging care.

Consider this challenge as part of Medicare for All: CAR T-cell immunotherapy for several refractory leukemias has front-end costs of $475,000, plus several hundred thousand dollars more if a patient experiences a severe form of cytokine release syndrome as a side effect. Roughly, 30% of those patients will fail to survive a year. If we have biomarkers and other medical criteria that can predict with 95% confidence which patients will be in that 30%, would a future possible version of yourself in that 30% group accept a rationing protocol that would deny yourself CAR T-cell therapy because for you it was “wasteful and inefficient”? In theory, 60,000 Americans each year would be candidates for this therapy; potential savings from that protocol would be $15 billion. Alternatively, call a friend with end-stage heart disease and ask if he would be willing to give up his $500,000 artificial heart so you can get CAR T-cell therapy.

If we aspire to be a just and caring society with limited resources (money) to meet unlimited health care needs, then we must have these painful public conversations. Moreover, these conversations must be rational and respectful. Current invisible rationing practices are nothing more than opioids for our consciences.

Fleck smallLeonard M. Fleck, PhD, is Acting Director and Professor in the Center for Ethics and Humanities in the Life Sciences and Professor in the Department of Philosophy at Michigan State University.

Join the discussion! Your comments and responses to this commentary are welcomed. The author will respond to all comments made by Thursday, March 7, 2019. With your participation, we hope to create discussions rich with insights from diverse perspectives.

You must provide your name and email address to leave a comment. Your email address will not be made public.

Click through to view references

Web of Interests Surrounding Medicines Makes Patient Access Increasingly Difficult

Bioethics in the News logoThis post is a part of our Bioethics in the News series

By Jennifer Carter-Johnson, PhD, JD

A recent New York Times article described the problems that patients are having gaining access to a new class of cholesterol reducers, called PCSK9 inhibitors. This difficulty extends not just to the uninsured but also to patients with insurance. The drug costs are exorbitant, listing as more than $14,000 per year for a drug that may need to be taken indefinitely. Insurance companies are balking at paying so much for the new drug when cheaper cholesterol reducers are available. Patients for whom the old cholesterol reducers do not work are forced to jump through many time-consuming hoops – mountains of paperwork, proof that other drugs have failed, and appeals after initial denials of coverage – before drug coverage approval for the PCSK9 inhibitors.

It is easy to blame the drug companies in this situation. Why must they charge so much?!?! This question has become more common considering recent news stories about drug company price increases designed only to increase profits. But high drug costs are only one obstacle for patients to access drugs. Insurance coverage dictates cost of drugs to patients from nominal co-pays to out-of-pocket self-funding. Attempts to address one issue without addressing the entire web of interests is doomed to failure.

8122717537_c2d86c7df9_h
Image description: A close-up photograph of a spider web that is covered in water droplets. The web takes up the entire frame and is in focus, the background is blurred and includes green and purple tones. Image source: nils.rohwer/Flickr Creative Commons

Drug Companies and Federal Regulations

Drugs cost money and time to develop and produce. All drugs must undergo scrutiny from the U.S. Food and Drug Administration, where drug developers must prove both the safety and efficacy of the potential drug before it is sold. The process takes on average 12 years between lead compound identification and final approval, and often costs close to a billion dollars absent streamlined approval processes for certain rare diseases. The billion-dollar cost estimate includes the cost of research for the failure of the many compounds that enter clinical trials but are deemed either unsafe or ineffective for the disease to be treated.

Thus, drug companies charge prices to recoup this huge research investment. Prices also pay for manufacturing and advertising as well as profit margins of close to 20% to fuel further investment. While there are mechanisms in place to incentivize generic drug manufacturers to enter the market and decrease prices through competition, branded drug companies have strategies to delay generic entry that have come under recent legal scrutiny.

Private Insurance and Federal/State Medical Programs

While drug costs are high due to the myriad factors described briefly above, patients are often insulated from some of those costs by insurance companies that cover the cost of drugs. Insurance comes in a variety of forms. Private insurance may be procured on the open market or through employer coverage. In the latter, the employer may cover some or all the costs of the insurance. Senior citizens rely on the Federally-sponsored Medicare program for medical coverage, though private supplements insurance policies are also the norm. Those too young for Medicare and too poor for private insurance (with or without an employer subsidy) are forced to rely on state Medicaid programs.

Unfortunately, not every insurance plan covers every drug. Insurance companies produce a formulary of covered drugs for each plan. The insurance plan negotiates a price, often significantly cheaper than the drug’s list price, that it will pay the drug manufacturer. More expensive drugs may require insurance pre-approval and multiple rounds of paperwork from the prescribing doctor.

Insurance companies have an incentive to reduce the usage of expensive drug alternatives. For private insurance companies, that incentive is profit. In fact, for-profit insurance companies know how to play this game quite well; many have profits in excess of 6 billion dollars. Medicaid and Medicare programs have limited budgets for all medical costs including drugs. While increased Medicaid funding for states offered through the Affordable Care Act was effective in decreasing uninsured rates, government funding is always in flux due to political pressures.

Doctors and Pharmacists

Doctors have great discretion in prescribing drugs. While doctors hold their patients’ health as the highest goal, knowledge of insurance (or its lack) may influence the doctor’s choice of drugs. Denial of a drug may well mean many, many more forms for a doctor who wants to make sure her patient has the best, most expensive drug. Doctors who do this for multiple patients could soon find themselves spending as much time on drug paperwork as medical care. Many doctors have taken to giving samples of drugs – left by drug companies as part of their advertising budgets – to patients who cannot afford the drug but need it.

Pharmacists exist at the epicenter of the patient’s dilemma. Patients often find out that insurance is not covering the drug when the pharmacist explains the situation. More troubling is the fact that drug prices are sometimes cheaper for a patient without insurance. For instance, a patient may have a twenty-dollar co-pay, but the drug may only cost ten dollars. For years, pharmacists have been subject to “gag clauses” in contracts between pharmacies and pharmacy benefit managers that prevent them from disclosing to the patient the cheaper alternative. Recent legislation signed this month has banned this practice.

Patients

Caught in this web of diverse and conflicting interests are the very people for whom drugs are created and vetted and prescribed – patients. Drug manufacturers must be able to recoup costs, but if no one can afford the drug how will they make sales? Additionally, drug pricing is a convoluted process that varies between insurance policies, pharmacies, and branded or generic formulations. Insurance coverage is often dictated by employer, age, or resources. Lack of coverage for a specific drug might mean the patient is faced with choosing a different drug or a different job. But asking about insurance formularies during a job interview would be quite difficult even if switching jobs in the midst of a medical crisis were possible. On the other hand, determining drug needs in advance is almost impossible. Finding a doctor with the time to work with a patient on an involved approval process is becoming more difficult given the increasing shortage of doctors in the United States.

Sitting in the center of this web of interests, patients have the most to gain and the most to lose from any overhaul of our drug system. It is impossible to fix all the problems by focusing only on the problems in one area. Unfortunately, patients are also a very small voice in the web that includes pharmaceutical companies, insurance companies, and medical professionals.

Jennifer Carter-Johnson photo

Jennifer Carter-Johnson, PhD, JD, is an Associate Professor of Law in the College of Law at Michigan State University. Dr. Carter-Johnson is a member of the Michigan State Bar and the Washington State Bar. She is registered to practice before the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office.

Join the discussion! Your comments and responses to this commentary are welcomed. The author will respond to all comments made by Thursday, November 1, 2018. With your participation, we hope to create discussions rich with insights from diverse perspectives.

You must provide your name and email address to leave a comment. Your email address will not be made public.

More Bioethics in the News from Dr. Carter-Johnson: Humanity in the Age of Genetic ModificationDefining The Spectrum of “Normal”: What is a Disease?Dawn of False Hope: Spread of “Right To Try” Laws across the U.S.Designing Children: Patents and the Market are not Sufficient Regulation

Click through to view references

Medicare Part “Q”: Fantasy or Fantastic?

Bioethics-in-the-News-logoThis post is a part of our Bioethics in the News series. For more information, click here.

By Leonard Fleck, PhD

In an essay in the New York Times (12/9/15) titled “Imagine a Medicare ‘Part Q’ for Quality at the End of Life,” Katy Butler tells the story of her father who suffered a devastating stroke at the age of 79. That was followed by additional strokes and vascular dementia that culminated in his death six and a half years later. She writes: “Ours is a story familiar to many families: shuttling my aged father to specialist after specialist, each focused on a single crumbling organ—his brain, his heart, his bladder, his colon, his eyes.” She goes on to write: “My father, and others like him, suffered because, at the tail end of life, Medicare continues to pay well for fix-it treatments focused unrealistically on cure and underpays for care and desperately needed home support.” Butler’s goal in writing this commentary is to advocate for a reversal of Medicare’s priorities: more emphasis on funding quality home care, quality primary care, and quality palliative care at the end of life rather than hospital-based or emergency room expensive, marginally effective life-prolonging but quality-of-life-diminishing curative efforts.

A similar story is told in another New York Times essay by Nina Bernstein (2014). She tells us about Mr. Joseph Andrey, 91 years old, beset with multiple chronic degenerative conditions, whose one wish was that he be allowed to die at home. The problem, however, was that multiple home care agencies refused to take him on as a home care patient because he was too complex a patient requiring too much care relative to the reimbursement they would receive from Medicare. Consequently, in the last two years of his life he endured multiple hospitalizations and nursing home placements that left him with a hospital-acquired sepsis and nursing home-acquired pressure sores. His daughter, who fought heroically to honor her father’s wishes, calculated that Medicare paid over a million dollars for “care” in the last two years of his life.

BeingMortalblog
“Being mortal is about the struggle to cope with the constraints of our biology, with the limits set by genes and cells and flesh and bone. […] But again and again, I have seen the damage we in medicine do when we fail to acknowledge that such power is finite and always will be.” -Atul Gawande in ‘Being Mortal.’ Image description: the cover of the book ‘Being Mortal’ by Atul Gawande. Photo courtesy of the Center for Ethics.

The story of Mr. Andrey is both sad and tragic. From a policy perspective we might think of him as an outlier, one of those rare anomalous cases that policies cannot accommodate. However, that would be a mistake. More than half of Medicare patients over age 85 have four or more incurable conditions, including what are described as “slowly fatal” conditions such as heart failure, emphysema, kidney failure, various advanced incurable cancers, and dementia. In 2014 roughly 6 million Medicare patients were over age 85. It strains the bounds of linguistic and ethical propriety to think of 3 million of these individuals as “outliers.”

I remind the reader that the major problem of health policy today is cost containment. Medicare is an inescapable focal point for that concern. In 2014 Medicare expenditures were about $640 billion. Over the ten-year period 2015-2024 projected Medicare expenditures are estimated to be $8.3 trillion. It is not as if all Medicare patients have extraordinary health needs. Rather, 5% of all Medicare patients account for 38% of total Medicare expenditures, roughly $256 billion in 2014 (National Institute for Health Care Management, 2012). If all those dollars were needed to address serious health needs, effectively restoring high quality life-years, a just society would have a presumptive ethical obligation to address those needs. But the stories of Mr. Andrey and Katy Butler’s father suggest that this is not often the case. Dr. Joanne Lynn, a veteran hospice physician, asks (no doubt in a frustrated tone of voice): “How can I get a $100,000 drug [for a terminal cancer patient] but I can’t get supper [for that same patient]?” She said that in the context of a federal budget sequestration that slashed spending on meals for seniors (Bernstein, 2014).

To return to Katy Butler, she is advocating for what she calls Medicare “Part Q” (for quality of life). Part Q would pay for a coordinated primary care team that would provide care in a patient’s home, what might be described as intense palliative and supportive care until that patient died. Such care would be provided for as long as two years prior to the death of a patient, most often with multiple slowly fatal medical conditions. To qualify for Medicare Part Q Butler says, “I would promise, upfront, to forgo medical treatments that evidence shows are outrageously expensive, not cost-effective, painful to endure, and likely to extend my life, if at all, by only months.” Medicare Part Q would be an option that patients would have to freely embrace. In spite of that qualification, it is easy to imagine death panel rhetoric being readily resurrected with the intent of scotching that option.

What we should note, however, is that under the Affordable Care Act the Obama Administration put in place three years ago a demonstration project under Medicare titled “Independent at Home.” About 8400 frail seniors with multiple chronic conditions are receiving customized home-based primary care, similar to what Katy Butler had in mind, except there is no requirement to forgo expensive and aggressive end of life care. Still, the goal of the program is to minimize use of emergency room and hospital services, thereby saving Medicare dollars. After one year the program has saved about $3100 per beneficiary.

I want to conclude with a provocative endorsement of Katy Butler’s Medicare Part Q. But I find it difficult to imagine what would motivate a substantial majority of Americans, likely within two years of dying, to forgo aggressive costly life-prolonging care (otherwise paid for by Medicare). Ms. Butler believes patients would vividly imagine the pain and suffering they could avoid for the sake of a dignified and peaceful death. But the sad reality is that most patients can imagine that pain and suffering but see it as something that can be endured for the sake of an indefinite gain in life expectancy, which is why so many cancer patients spend only the last week or two of their lives in hospice.

To correct for that distorted judgment I would offer a provocative addendum to Part Q, namely, that patients would receive 25% of whatever they saved the Medicare program. If they gave up a $100,000 cancer drug for their metastatic cancer, they would receive $25,000. Presumably another $25,000 or more of that savings would pay for intensive in-home palliative care and supportive social care. Physicians would have to be entrusted with responsibility for protecting the best medical interests of those patients, i.e., dissuading patients from inappropriately foregoing a necessary hospitalization that was congruent with a dignified dying process. Still, my critics might see this proposal as fundamentally ethically flawed, manipulating patients with a monetary offering so that they would give up some portion of their remaining life. But if medical research shows in some range of definable terminal circumstances that higher costs are associated with a worse quality of death, then that is ethically significant. Some research shows just that (See Zhang et al., 2009; De Jonge et al., 2014; Boling and Leff, 2014; Meier, 2015). If such economic incentives serve to nudge patients to make choices that are more congruent with their objective best interests near the end of life, and if those savings can be reallocated to higher priority (more just and more cost-effective) health care needs of the elderly, then this proposal deserves thoughtful consideration rather than rhetorical savaging.

For my physician readers I will conclude with this question: Would you be comfortable counseling patients likely in the last year of life regarding this option, i.e., being a bit more directive?

Leonard FleckLeonard Fleck, PhDis a Professor in the Center for Ethics and Humanities in the Life Sciences and the Department of Philosophy at Michigan State University. Dr. Fleck is the author of Just Caring: Health Care Rationing and Democratic Deliberation (Oxford University Press; 2009).

Join the discussion! Your comments and responses to this commentary are welcomed. The author will respond to all comments made by Thursday, March 10, 2016. With your participation, we hope to create discussions rich with insights from diverse perspectives.

You must provide your name and email address to leave a comment. Your email address will not be made public.

Click through to view references

Bioethics for Breakfast: Controlling Medicare Costs: What Are the Options? What Is Fair?

bioethics-for-breakfastLeonard M. Fleck, PhD, and Tom Marks presented at Thursday morning’s Bioethics for Breakfast event, offering views on the topic, “Controlling Medicare Costs: What Are the Options? What Is Fair?”

An October 2013 Health Affairs article projected that total Medicare spending for the next ten-year period would be close to $8.5 trillion. This is obviously a large portion of federal spending over that period of time and a substantial contributor to the federal deficit problem. What should be done to address this issue fairly and compassionately?

In the discussion, speakers and attendees explored a range of options for controlling future Medicare costs.  These included raising the age of eligibility for Medicare, raising the Medicare payroll tax by one percentage point, raising Medicare premiums and co-payments for beneficiaries, reducing payments to providers, bargaining more effectively with pharmaceutical companies, and endorsing a “defined benefit” approach to Medicare (often referred to as the Ryan plan).  It was noted that some of these options are seriously deficient from the perspective of health care justice.  It was also noted that Medicare reform must include both revenue enhancement and substantial cost control in order to keep Medicare sustainable far into the future.  It was concluded that no one policy option will magically fix Medicare, that multiple policies will need to be adopted, some of which will be morally and politically painful.  The key to achieving this will be honest, rational, and mutually respectful public conversation, as opposed to often vicious and disingenuous rhetoric that has been the currency of debate thus far.

Leonard M. Fleck, Ph.D.
Leonard M. Fleck is a Professor of Philosophy and Medical Ethics at the Center for Ethics and Humanities in the Life Sciences, College of Human Medicine, Michigan State University. He is the author of Just Caring: Health Care Rationing and Democratic Deliberation (Oxford University Press, 2009).

Tom Marks
Tom Marks is a principal from the Lansing, Michigan office of Health Management Associates and is one of the firm’s leading experts in public reimbursement policy. Since joining HMA in February 2013, Tom has worked extensively with hospitals and health systems around the country on payment reform and other financial matters. Tom spent more than 20 years at the University of Michigan Health System in various financial leadership roles.

About Bioethics for Breakfast:

In 2010, Hall, Render, Killian, Heath & Lyman invited the Center for Ethics to partner on a bioethics seminar series. The Center for Ethics and Hall Render invite guests from the health professions, religious and community organizations, political circles, and the academy to engage in lively discussions of topics spanning the worlds of bioethics, health law, business, and policy. For each event, the Center selects from a wide range of controversial issues and provides two presenters either from our own faculty or invited guests, who offer distinctive, and sometimes clashing, perspectives. Those brief presentations are followed by a moderated open discussion.

Just Caring: Meeting the Health Care Needs of the Elderly (and Everyone Else)

Bioethics-in-the-News-logo-smallThis post is a part of our Bioethics in the News series. For more information, click here.

By Leonard Fleck, PhD

In the early 1970s we were talking about “lifeboat ethics.”  If we could not feed everyone in lifeboat Earth, then who should we throw out?  As we move further into the 21st century we seem to be pondering “fiscal cliff ethics.”  Who should be thrown over the fiscal cliff in order to save the economy as a whole?  Neither of these “ethical perspectives” should be thought reasonable, but much less necessary.

We in the US have a serious problem of health care cost escalation overall, but it is especially acute with regard to the elderly and the federal budget.  In 2012 the total costs of the Medicare program will be a bit under $600 billion.  Over the next ten years the most reliable projections put average annual growth of Medicare expenditures at 6.1%. That means Medicare will cost a bit over $1.1 trillion in 2022.  The ten-year cost of the program will be about $8.7 trillion.

There are three major factors that are driving Medicare costs upward.  These are: (1) the aging out of the “baby boom” generation, (2) costly new medical technologies, and (3) an increasing burden of chronic illness among the elderly (generated to a large extent by costly new life-prolonging medical technologies).  Nothing can be done about the first factor.  About 80 million baby boomers will join Medicare between 2010 and 2030.  And they will live longer than any other generation of the elderly.  So cost control efforts will have to be directed elsewhere.

Uwe Reinhardt, a Princeton economist, has called our attention to two “Great Equations”:  Cost Control = Income Control; Cost Control = Care Control.  These equations tell us where the major political challenges are in controlling Medicare costs.  Our concern, however, is with the moral challenges of cost control.  How should we assess from a moral point of view, the point of view of what a just and caring society ought to choose, the various options for cost control suggested by the quoted experts in the Kaiser Health News?

Joseph Antos, an economist at the American Enterprise Institute, is an advocate for a “defined contribution subsidy” to controlling Medicare costs.  This is the basic mechanism for controlling costs advocated by Paul Ryan, former vice-presidential candidate.  The major economic advantage of this option is that it would effectively control future Medicare costs, i.e., costs to the federal government.  It would do very little to control overall health care costs because that would fly in the face of conservative free market principles.  Instead, the value of the voucher or subsidy would be gradually eroded relative to medical inflation.  That would mean that Medicare recipients would be able to buy health plans that offered less and less in the way of accessible medical services.

Private insurance plans might be legally obligated to offer plans that covered some fairly substantial package of Medicare benefits, but plans might have extraordinarily high copayments and deductibles such that access to costly but effective medical care was essentially rationed by ability to pay.  The political advantage of this approach is that advocates can say government is not rationing care; Medicare recipients are freely making rationing decisions for themselves.  This is hidden or invisible rationing, which is intrinsically unjust.  Of course, if the care that Medicare recipients were denying themselves were marginally beneficial, non-costworthy care, then the moral objections would be largely dissipated.  But the economically less well-off would not be able to make such distinctions; they would be denying themselves as often as not effective costworthy medical interventions as well as non-costworthy interventions.  In short, the current basic equity of the Medicare program would end and access to needed health care for the elderly would reflect the differential access to care determined by individual ability to pay characteristic of the rest of the insurance market.

Bruce Vladeck, former administrator of the Health Care Financing Administration , argues for giving the Medicare program the power to bargain with pharmaceutical companies for discounts that reflected the purchasing power of fifty million participants.  This is what is currently forbidden by law, thanks to the lobbying efforts of representatives of medical device and pharmaceutical companies.  Such bargaining would yield substantial benefits for all Medicare recipients as well as the federal government.  So this recommendation is morally desirable.  The counter argument is that this will slow dramatically drug research and discovery.  The response to that objection is that most of the drugs generated by the pharmaceutical industry over the past fifteen years have proven to be extraordinarily expensive and mostly marginally beneficial.  There are better investments for those health care dollars than those drugs.

Other respondents in Kaiser News advocate for abandoning the fee-for-service mechanism for financing health care services because that motivates physicians to provide more care that yields little benefit.  Accountable Care Organizations are supposed to be able to provide care more efficiently and with higher quality.  But this will require enormous reorganization of our health care system.  It will likely mean some decline in income for many physicians in medical specialty and sub-specialty areas, in part because a lot of their more routine medical work can be carried out by primary care physicians with some additional training.  An outcome such as that is hardly of moral concern, given the income disparities between these sub-specialists in the US and their European and Canadian analogues.

More generally, several respondents emphasized the need for greater coordination of care, especially for individuals with complex chronic conditions.  Greater efficiency is supposed to be the (morally) painless descent down from the fiscal cliff.  This strategy also emphasizes eliminating waste and fraud in Medicare.  However, identifying “waste” is not as morally benign an effort as this language might suggest.  Approximately 28% of Medicare spending is for patients in the last six months of life, which comes to $2.3 trillion over our ten-year period.  Is all of that “wasteful”?  Or is the more accurate description “marginally beneficial”?

The language of waste disguises the moral issues; the language of marginal benefit forces us to face those issues.  Efficiency efforts achieve one-time savings.  Such efforts fail to address the upward cost pressures generated by new medical technologies.  The just use of those technologies requires, to my mind, a painful public conversation about what we are willing to deny our future possible terminally ill selves in the way of extraordinarily costly marginally beneficial medical care.  This is correctly described as health care rationing, but it is an honest and equitable and reasonable approach to rationing as opposed to the dishonest, inequitable, and unreasonable rationing implicit in proposed Medicare vouchers.  The latter approach does represent fiscal cliff ethics; poorer vulnerable elderly patients are thrown over the fiscal cliff to protect publicly funded access to expensive marginally beneficial care for the well-off in our society.  A just and caring society must do better than that.

This post was written in response to the article “Medicare Silver Bullets: What’s the Best Way to Control Costs?” published on the Kaiser Health News website on December 12, 2012.

Fleck small

Leonard Fleck, PhD, is a Professor in the Center for Ethics and Humanities in the Life Sciences and the Department of Philosophy at Michigan State University.

Join the discussion! Your comments and responses to this commentary are welcomed. The author will respond to all comments made by Friday, January 18. With your participation, we hope to create discussions rich with insights from diverse perspectives.

You must provide your name and email address to leave a comment. Your email address will not be made public.